Другие статьи

Цель нашей работы - изучение аминокислотного и минерального состава травы чертополоха поникшего
2010

Слово «этика» произошло от греческого «ethos», что в переводе означает обычай, нрав. Нравы и обычаи наших предков и составляли их нравственность, общепринятые нормы поведения.
2010

Артериальная гипертензия (АГ) является важнейшей медико-социальной проблемой. У 30% взрослого населения развитых стран мира определяется повышенный уровень артериального давления (АД) и у 12-15 % - наблюдается стойкая артериальная гипертензия
2010

Целью нашего исследования явилось определение эффективности применения препарата «Гинолакт» для лечения ВД у беременных.
2010

Целью нашего исследования явилось изучение эффективности и безопасности препарата лазолван 30мг у амбулаторных больных с ХОБЛ.
2010

Деформирующий остеоартроз (ДОА) в настоящее время является наиболее распространенным дегенеративно-дистрофическим заболеванием суставов, которым страдают не менее 20% населения земного шара.
2010

Целью работы явилась оценка анальгетической эффективности препарата Кетанов (кеторолак трометамин), у хирургических больных в послеоперационном периоде и возможности уменьшения использования наркотических анальгетиков.
2010

Для более объективного подтверждения мембранно-стабилизирующего влияния карбамезапина и ламиктала нами оценивались перекисная и механическая стойкости эритроцитов у больных эпилепсией
2010

Нами было проведено клинико-нейропсихологическое обследование 250 больных с ХИСФ (работающих в фосфорном производстве Каратау-Жамбылской биогеохимической провинции)
2010


C использованием разработанных алгоритмов и моделей был произведен анализ ситуации в системе здравоохранения биогеохимической провинции. Рассчитаны интегрированные показатели здоровья
2010

Специфические особенности Каратау-Жамбылской биогеохимической провинции связаны с производством фосфорных минеральных удобрений.
2010

Tax evasion, currency demand and the shadow economy: the case of Kazakhstan

Abstract. The fact that a not inconsiderable sector of Kazakhstan's economy has been the shadow economy is a consequence of the economic and social policy that the government pursued from 2002 to 2015. This article presents the outcomes of the attempts to define the scope and to trace the evolution of the shadow economy in Kazakhstan. The author also estimates the negative effect the shadow economy had on the tax revenue to the national budget during this period. The findings reveal decreasing trends in the shadow economy in general and tax evasion in particular, yet still they were a huge proportion of the national GDP; amounting, according to the author, to about 30.22% and 2.5% of Kazakhstan’s GDP in 2015, respectively.

Introduction

It is a well established fact that informal activities are on the rise around the world, particularly in developing countries. The estimates made by Schneider and Enste [1] for

IMF reports say that the size of the shadow economy in developing countries ranges from 35 to 44 percent of GDP whereas the same for transition and OECD countries ranges from 21 to 30 percent and 14 to 16 percent respectively. There are several reasons, in turn, why policy makers should be concerned about the rise of the hidden economy: (1) informal activities reduce the tax base, thereby limiting the financing of public goods and social protection [2]; (2) a growing hidden economy may distort official indicators, resulting in inefficient allocation of public resources [3]; and (3) a prospering hidden economy may attract workers away from the formal sector and create an unfair competition environment for formal firms [3].

The literature indicates that a growth in of the underground economy leads to reduced state revenues which in turn reduce the quality and quantity of publicly provided goods and services. Ultimately, this can lead to an increase in the tax rates for firms and individuals in the official sector, quite often combined with a deterioration in the quality of public goods (such as the public infrastructure) and of the administration, with the consequence of even stronger incentives to participate in the shadow economy. Johnson et al. [4] present a simple model of this relationship. Their findings show that smaller underground economies appear in countries with higher tax revenues, if achieved by lower tax rates, fewer laws and regulations and less bribery facing enterprises. Countries with a better rule of law, which is financed by tax revenues, also have smaller underground economies. Transition countries have higher levels of regulation leading to a significantly higher incidence of bribery, higher effective taxes on official activities and a large discretionary framework of regulations, and consequently to a higher shadow economy.

Most of the studies on the underground economy are limited in the main to developed countries and only a few, such as Osoro [5], Schneider [6], Faal [7] are devoted to the developing world. The empirical evidence of Kazakhstan,s shadow economy has been studied only by Schneider [8], but empirical estimates of the shadow economy,s relationship with tax evasion do not exist. This study, therefore, is the first to empirically apply a currency demand model to estimate the relationship of shadow economy size with tax evasion in Kazakhstan.

Materials and Methods

A method that has been widely used among the indirect approaches is the currency demand approach . This method associates the excessive use of cash in the economy with a greater number of informal activities, and was first proposed by Cagan [9] in his study about the determinants of the stock of money in the United States. Later, Gutmann [10] and Tanzi [11] further developed this approach, assuming that the informal economy is a response to the tax burden and is generally channeled through cash. A correctly defined currency demand function should include, then, fiscal variables as proxies of the tax burden, whose parameters capture the sensitivity of the use of currency to changes in these variables. This allows us to distinguish the fraction of currency demanded for formal and informal activities and to convert the latter into income from informal activities using an appropriate measure of income

  1. For a detailed survey of the different methods of estimation of the informal economy, see Gerxhani (1999) and Schneider and Enste (2000).
  2. Parallel to these authors, Feige (1980) derived an index of informality under his general currency-demand deposit ratio model (GCDRM), where informal transactions are not necessarily in cash
  3. In developing countries, several individuals usually carry out more than one economic activity.

following this monetary approach include Bhattacharyya [12], Spiro [13], Ahumada et al. [14], Schneider [15], and Gadea and Serrano- Sanz [16].

In the currency demand approach, the term informal sector or hidden economy refers, then, to all activity that adds value but is not taxed or registered, and consequently is beyond official channels of measurement. This definition follows the widely accepted legal approach to informality. More specifically, economic agents rationally choose to partially or completely engage in informal activities by weighting the costs and benefits that a legal status entails. Formal or informal are then the different activities carried out by individuals, so an economic agent may comply with all the government-imposed taxes and regulations in one market but may not in another * . The currency demand approach, however, has also been subject to several criticisms [17; 18]. As pointed out by Gadea and Serrano- Sanz [16], most of the criticisms are related to the sensitivity of the results to the basic assumptions of the model. For example, the assumption that most of the hidden transactions are in cash. Similarly, the monetary aggregate used in the estimation process and the corresponding velocity of circulation, as well as the assumption of a similar velocity of circulation in both formal and informal activities. Finally, the identification of an appropriate fiscal vawhere that iws hthe er eo bservise dth preferences leading inform ale a ctii nvfiotirems al activit also be difficult. From equatiFornom(3)e,q wuaetiaorne

In the literature econo mies,a ethcoe nfo mrmieasl, athned to measure the sizethe m inimumth e v amluineism, uwme av r economy over timextra curren ecxytrian caunrrencocyn o Kazakhstan, we ap info rmal trainnsfaocrtmio anls t.r ansa method. The pioneers in application of this method were Cagan [9] for the case of the United States followed by Gutmann [10] and Feige [19]. Tanzi [20] further developed this approach by assuming that the tax burden is one of the core causes of the shadow economy which is then channeled through the excessive demand and use of cash. The main assumption is that informal transactions conducted in the shadow economy are mainly in cash in order to avoid any trace of evidence for the official authorities. Any excess demand of cash is then attributed to the variables controlling the shadow economy. In that sense, an increase in informal activities in an economy would lead to an excessive use of cash. Therefore, if we can estimate the amount of excessive cash used in informal activities, then we can estimate the size of the shadow economy by multiplying the amount of cash used in the shadow economy by the income velocity of money.

Formally, there are two steps when estimating the size of the shadow economy by the CDA. The first step is estimating the demand for currency, both for the formal transactions in an economy and also for the informal ones involving the motivation to cover up income. Following the typical Cagan [9] and Ahumada et al. [14] currency demand function,(1) orrbesnecrvy eidn creuarrl etnecrmy sin, Tre i asl ate frimscsa,l Tvaisri ab flies craelavtaer real terms, T is a fiscal variable related to the )le wtoe easrtei mabalte itoo e swtihmic ahte isv thewahmicohu inst tohfe caumrroe ramdoalwa encd o snhoamdoiews. eTchoen no,m wiehse.n T when s , ewt thheeniwncee ns uaebsl,e wtoe oabreta ainble to.Tobhtea idniffere. nTchee b deitfwf eren ce ba ya,n i.ec.otnh oemilyle, gi.ael.i mthoe n eilyle ugsael dm ionntehye us sheadd oinwthe ons.nomies. Then, when we set the incentive namofettehres apnardamis epteorssitaivned ains dp osfitiisveneagnadtivoef. iIsn n teh umthed lethvaetl aosf thaexalteivoQenUlA oRTrER gtLYao AxvNaAeLtYriTnoICmnAL eRoEnrV tIEWionvter1vn (6em5n)/2et0i1n7ot

to conduct informal

Results and Discussion

Tfiscal wvariable setit e is
lev elifof taxation or

Where is total currency in real terms at time t , is the fiscal variable, either taxes overG DP.s In th e equa tion , th eo expected signs of 1 2 β , β and 4 β coefficients are positive and the expected sign of β 3 coefficient is negative. ro T hes r esults of th eunitlroottest sho w tha t the r nulle h ypothesisof nounittrootrwas lrejec ted at the 95 %cconfidencealevel. The variables were nnon estatio narye aat leve lian d owerenu there fore first torder differentia ted after which they became stationary. The study then proceeded to estimate

an OLS model which regresses the first differentiated log of total currency outside the banking system on the first differentiated independentuvaria bles as in equation (1). The estimated equations for the currency demand function are presented below.

The data used for the analysis is annual and covers the period from 2002 to 2015, with the aim of having a sufficiently broad sample period whic hisp usual iun der ithiss a pproa ch.er this approga

Taking logs to both sides of (1), the estimated eq ua tion of thetdemand fortcurren cy ise given by,

governm ent inte rvention increases,iin dividuals are encouraged (or have greater incentives) to engage in informal activities which are facilitated with the suse sof currency. s nega ve. that as the level of taxation or government interven ve gTheestudynthen) proceeded toncalculatetithe level of tax evasion. In other words, the amount of tax revenue lost as a result of the shadow economy. uGiv ene avera ge ttax e(T),o ta xnr even ue lost was sderived e as the product of the avera getax an dv theg un der ground GDP. round GDP.

variable (T) to the minimum values, we are
able to obtain M_0^1. The difference between
M_0 and M_0^1 gives us the extra currency
ina nueconomy , ei.e .ethe, illegal fmon eyrused in
the shadow economy
transactions.stimate
an
In s theo case nof the
as sum edle thatbasn the
.

15, with tStandard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

The results showed that the model met they req uirem ents. Expected signs for the variables of the model are as required and all variables are statistically significant apart from taxes. In the model, after estimating the parameters of the above equation, currency in circulation is estimated by using relevant variable s. T hen, .currency in circulation is estima ted eagaine by imposing zero tax rate value. The difference between these two estimates represents the volume of currency ina circulationtinthe underground economy. Multiply ing thise difference with the velocity of money yieldsS the nominal aggregate of theunde rgroundeconomy.

d eTablenfSizeeand development of the Kazakhstan shadow economy in % of GDP using CDA

 

Figure 1 A comparison of the size and development of the Kazakhstan shadow economy using the CDA and MIMIC model, 2002 to 2015

The estimated size of the shadow economy in Kazakhstan as a percentage of GDP is about 30 %, the corporate tax rate is about 0.85 %, VAT is 1.36% and the income tax rate is about 0.32 % at 2015 rates. On average for 20022015 as a percentage of GDP, it is about 42.74 % on average and about 35.8 % in the works by Schneider.

Conclusion

The estimation of the shadow economy by the use of the Currency Demand Approach as CARRIET out in this study oversimplifies the real economy. As pointed out by Schneider and Enste [1; 21] there are many substantial drawbacks to this approach. These include the assumption that there is an absence of any transactions in the underground economy in a given base year, that the velocity of money in both the official and the irregular economy are the same and that the excessive tax burden is the only determinant of the shadow economy. Several other variables determine the level of shadow economy which include the following: the level of GDP per capita, the level of unemployment, the level of business regulation, the level of corruption, the size of government and the quality level of public services. This study, however, sought to emphasize the impact of taxes, hence the high level of emphasis on the role of average taxes. The results obtained do not vary greatly from those obtained from major studies by Schneider [6;9]. The estimates however obtained are slightly higher, at about 30.22 % on average for the shadow economy, with Schneider estimating a value of about 33.8% for the year 2015. About 2.5 % of state revenue is lost as a result of the presence of the shadow economy.

 

REFERENCES:

  1. Schneider, F., Enste, D., 2002. The Shadow Economy: Theoretical Approaches, Empirical Studies, and Political Implications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
  2. Loayza, Norman V. 1996. “The Economics of the Informal Sector: A Simple Model and Some Empirical Evidence from Latin America,” Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Series Public Policy, 45, pp. 129–62.
  3. Schneider, F., 2000. The increase of the size of the shadow economy of 18 OECD Countries: some preliminary explanations. Paper presented at the Annual Public Choice Meeting, Charleston, SC.
  4. Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., Zoido-Lobato´n, P., 1998b. Corruption, public finances and the unofficial economy.
  5. Osoro, E. Nehemiah (1995), “Tax Reforms in Tanzania: Motivations, Directions and Implications,” African Economic Research Consortium (AERC), Research Paper No. 38.
  6. Schneider, F. (2007): Shadow Economies and Corruption all Over the World: New Estimates for 145 Countries. Economics, 2007–9, July 2007.
  7. Ebrima A Faal, 2003. "Currency Demand, the Underground Economy, and, Tax Evasionae” The Case of Guyana," IMF Working Papers 03/7, International Monetary Fund.
  8. Schneider, F. and Buehn, A. (2009). Shadow Economies and Corruption All
  9. Over the World: Revised Estimates for 120 Countries. Economics: The OpenAccess, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 1, 2007-9 (Version 2).
  10. Cagan, P., 1958. The demand for currency relative to the total money supply. Journal of Political Economy 66, 302– 328.
  11. Guttman, M. (1977) "The subterranean economy", Financial Analysts Journal, 34, pp. 24-27.
  12. Tanzi, V., 1980. The underground economy in the United States: estimates and implications. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro 135, 427– 453.
  13. Bhattacharyya, D.K. (1990) "An econometric method of estimating the ‘underground economy’, United Kingdom (1960-1984): estimates and tests", Economic Journal, Vol. 100, No. 402, pp. 703-717.
  14. Spiro, Peter S. (1994) “Estimating the Underground Economy: a Critical Evaluation of the Monetary Approach,” paper presented at the 28th annual meeting of the Canadian Economics Association, University of Calgary, June, forthcoming, Canadian Tax Journal, 42, No. 4
  15. Ahumada, H., Facundo, A., Canavese A., Canavese, P., 2004. The demand for currency approach and the size of the shadow economy: a critical assessment. Discussion Paper, Delta Ecole Normale Superieure, Paris.
  16. Schneider, F., 2003. The shadow economy. In: Rowley, C.K., Schneider, F. (Eds.), Encyclopedia of Public Choice. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht. 16. Mariá Dolores Gadea & José Mariá Serrano-Sanz, 2002. "The hidden economy in Spain - A monetary estimation, 1964-1998," Empirical Economics, Springer, vol. 27(3), pages 499-527.
  17. Thomas, J. (1999) "Quantifying the black economy: ‘measurement without theory’, yet again?" Economic Journal, Vol. 109, June, pp. 381-389.
  18. Giles, D.E.A. (1999a) "Modelling the hidden economy and the tax-gap in New Zealand", Empirical Economics, 24, pp. 621-640.
  19. Feige, E. L. (1979) "How big is the irregular economy?", Challenge, 22, pp. 5-13.
  20. Tanzi, V., 1983. The underground economy in the United States: annual estimates, 1930–1980. IMF Staff Papers 30, 283–305.
  21. Schneider, F., Enste, D., 2000. Shadow economies: size, causes, and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature 38, 77–114.
  22. Gerxhani, K., 2003. The informal sector in developed and less-developed countries: a literature survey. Public Choice 114, 295– 318.

Разделы знаний

International relations

International relations

Law

Philology

Philology is the study of language in oral and written historical sources; it is the intersection between textual criticism, literary criticism, history, and linguistics.[

Technical science

Technical science